Scrigroup - Documente si articole

Username / Parola inexistente      

Home Documente Upload Resurse Alte limbi doc  
BulgaraCeha slovacaCroataEnglezaEstonaFinlandezaFranceza
GermanaItalianaLetonaLituanianaMaghiaraOlandezaPoloneza
SarbaSlovenaSpaniolaSuedezaTurcaUcraineana

AdministrationAnimalsArtBiologyBooksBotanicsBusinessCars
ChemistryComputersComunicationsConstructionEcologyEconomyEducationElectronics
EngineeringEntertainmentFinancialFishingGamesGeographyGrammarHealth
HistoryHuman-resourcesLegislationLiteratureManagementsManualsMarketingMathematic
MedicinesMovieMusicNutritionPersonalitiesPhysicPoliticalPsychology
RecipesSociologySoftwareSportsTechnicalTourismVarious

The Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

economy



+ Font mai mare | - Font mai mic



The Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment




WHATS NEW IN THE THIRD EDITION:

There is a new In the News box on 'The Case for Inflation Targeting.'

LEARNING OBJECTIVES:

By the end of this chapter, students should understand:

Ø      why policymakers face a short-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment.

Ø      why the inflation-unemployment tradeoff disappears in the long run.

Ø      how supply shocks can shift the inflation-unemployment tradeoff.

Ø      the short-run cost of reducing inflation.

Ø      how policymakers credibility might affect the cost of reducing inflation.

CONTEXT AND PURPOSE:

Chapter 22 is the final chapter in a three-chapter sequence on the economys short-run fluctuations around its long-term trend. Chapter 20 introduced aggregate supply and aggregate demand. Chapter 21 developed how monetary and fiscal policy affect aggregate demand. Both Chapters 20 and 21 addressed the relationship between the price level and output. Chapter 22 will concentrate on a similar relationship between inflation and unemployment.

The purpose of Chapter 22 is to trace the history of economists thinking about the relationship between inflation and unemployment. Students will see why there is a temporary tradeoff between inflation and unemployment, and why there is no permanent tradeoff. This result is an extension of the results produced by the model of aggregate supply and aggregate demand where a change in the price level induced by a change in aggregate demand temporarily alters output but has no permanent impact on output.

KEY POINTS:

The Phillips curve describes a negative relationship between inflation and unemployment. By expanding aggregate demand, policymakers can choose a point on the Phillips curve with higher inflation and lower unemployment. By contracting aggregate demand, policymakers can choose a point on the Phillips curve with lower inflation and higher unemployment.

The tradeoff between inflation and unemployment described by the Phillips curve holds only in the short run. In the long run, expected inflation adjusts to changes in actual inflation, and the short-run Phillips curve shifts. As a result, the long-run Phillips curve is vertical at the natural rate of unemployment.

The short-run Phillips curve also shifts because of shocks to aggregate supply. An adverse supply shock, such as the increase in world oil prices during the 1970s, gives policymakers a less favorable tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. That is, after an adverse supply shock, policymakers have to accept a higher rate of inflation for any given rate of unemployment, or a higher rate of unemployment for any given rate of inflation.

When the Fed contracts growth in the money supply to reduce inflation, it moves the economy along the short-run Phillips curve, which results in temporarily high unemployment. The cost of disinflation depends on how quickly expectations of inflation fall. Some economists argue that a credible commitment to low inflation can reduce the cost of disinflation by inducing a quick adjustment of expectations.

CHAPTER OUTLINE:

I.  The Phillips Curve

A.  Origins of the Phillips Curve

In 1958, an economist named A. W. Phillips published an article discussing the negative correlation between inflation rates and unemployment rates in the United Kingdom.

American economists Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow showed a similar relationship between inflation and unemployment for the United States two years later.

The belief was that low unemployment is related to high aggregate demand, and high aggregate demand puts upward pressure on prices. Likewise, high unemployment is related to low aggregate demand, and low aggregate demand pulls price levels down.

Definition of Phillips curve: a curve that shows the short-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment.

Figure 1

 


Samuelson and Solow believed that the Phillips curve offered policymakers a menu of possible economic outcomes. Policymakers could use monetary and fiscal policy to choose any point on the curve.

Activity 1 Inflation and Unemployment

Type: In-Class demonstration

Topics: graphing, Phillips curve

Materials needed: none

Time: 7 minutes

Class limitations: works in any size class

Purpose

This activity leads students from a simple graphing review to the concept of the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment in the short run.

Instructions

Ask the students to graph the following points and to describe the relation they see.

Inflation Unemployment (Year)

5.4% 5.5% 1990

4.2 6.7 1991

2.9 7.4 1992

Points for Discussion

These points illustrate an inverse relation, or a negative slope, where increases in one variable are associated with decreases in the other. This tradeoff between inflation and unemployment is not a long-run phenomenon, of course, but it is regularly found in the short run. This can be a way to discuss policy tradeoffs. Since 1992 was an election year, this exercise can be used to show the dangers of a high unemployment rate to the reelection of an incumbent president.

 


B. Aggregate Demand, Aggregate Supply, and the Phillips Curve

Figure 2

 



The Phillips curve shows the combinations of inflation and unemployment that arise in the short run due to shifts in the aggregate demand curve.

The greater the aggregate demand for goods and services, the greater the economys output and the higher the price level. Greater output means lower unemployment. Whatever the previous years price level happens to be, the higher the price level in the current year, the higher the rate of inflation.

Example: The price level is 100 (measured by the Consumer Price Index) in the year 2000. There are two possible changes in the economy for the year 2001: a low level of aggregate demand or a high level of aggregate demand.

a. If the economy experiences a low level of aggregate demand, we would be at a short-run equilibrium like point A. This point also corresponds with point A on the Phillips curve. Note that when aggregate demand is low, the inflation rate is relatively low and the unemployment rate is relatively high.

b. If the economy experiences a high level of aggregate demand, we would be at a short-run equilibrium like point B. This point also corresponds with point B on the Phillips curve. Note that when aggregate demand is high, the inflation rate is relatively high and the unemployment rate is relatively low.

Given that monetary and fiscal policy can both shift the aggregate-demand curve, these types of policies can move the economy along the Phillips curve.

a. Increases in the money supply, increases in government spending, or decreases in taxes all increase aggregate demand and move the economy to a point on the Phillips curve with lower unemployment and higher inflation.

b. Decreases in the money supply, decreases in government spending, or increases in taxes all lower aggregate demand and move the economy to a point on the Phillips curve with higher unemployment and lower inflation.

II. Shifts in the Phillips Curve: The Role of Expectations

A.  The Long-Run Phillips Curve

Figure 3

 


In 1968, economist Milton Friedman argued that monetary policy is only able to choose a combination of unemployment and inflation for a short period of time. At the same time, economist Edmund Phelps wrote a paper suggesting the same thing.

This is true because, in the long run, monetary growth has no real effects. This means that it cannot affect the factors that determine the economys unemployment rate.

Thus, in the long run, we would not expect there to be a relationship between unemployment and inflation. This must mean that, in the long run, the Phillips curve is vertical.

Figure 4

 


The vertical Phillips curve occurs because, in the long run, the aggregate supply curve is vertical as well. Thus, increases in aggregate demand lead only to changes in the price level and have no effect on the economys level of output. Thus, in the long run, unemployment will not change when aggregate demand changes, but inflation will.

The long-run aggregate-supply curve occurs at the economys natural rate of output; thus, the long-run Phillips curve occurs at the natural rate of unemployment.



B. Expectations and the Short-Run Phillips Curve

The short-run aggregate supply curve is upward sloping because of misperceptions about relative prices, sticky wages, and sticky prices. These perceptions, wages, and prices adjust over time, so that the positive relationship between the price level and the quantity of goods and services supplied occurs only in the short run.

This same logic applies to the Phillips curve. The tradeoff between inflation and unemployment holds only in the short run.

The expected level of inflation is an important factor in understanding the difference between the long-run and the short-run Phillips curves. Expected inflation measures how much people expect the overall price level to change.

The expected rate of inflation is one variable that determines the position of the short-run aggregate-supply curve. This is true because the expected price level affects the perceptions of relative prices that people form and the wages and prices that they set.

In the short-run, peoples expectations are somewhat fixed. Thus, when the Fed increases the money supply, aggregate demand increases along the upward sloping short-run aggregate-supply curve. Output grows (unemployment falls) and the price level rises (inflation increases).

Eventually, however, people will respond by changing their expectations of the price level. Specifically, they will begin expecting a higher rate of inflation.

We can relate the actual unemployment rate to the natural rate of unemployment, the actual inflation rate, and the expected inflation rate using the following equation:

 


a.           Because expected inflation is already given in the short run, higher actual inflation leads to lower unemployment.

b. How much unemployment changes in response to a change in inflation is determined by the variable , which is related to the slope of the short-run aggregate-supply curve.


Figure 5

 


8. If policymakers want to take advantage of the short-run tradeoff between unemployment and inflation, it may lead to negative consequences.

a. Suppose the economy is at point A and policymakers wish to lower the unemployment rate. Expansionary monetary policy or fiscal policy is used to shift aggregate demand to the right. The economy moves to point B, with a lower unemployment rate and a higher rate of inflation.

b. Over time, people get used to this new level of inflation and raise their expectations of inflation. This leads to an upward shift of the short-run Phillips curve. The economy ends up at point C, with a higher inflation rate than at point A, but the same level of unemployment.

C.  The Natural Experiment for the Natural-Rate Hypothesis

Definition of the natural-rate hypothesis: the claim that unemployment eventually returns to its normal, or natural rate, regardless of the rate of inflation.

Figure 6

 


Figure 6 shows the unemployment rate and inflation rate from 1961 to 1968. It is easy to see the inverse relationship between these two variables.

Beginning in the late 1960s, the government followed policies that increased aggregate demand.

a. Government spending rose because of the Vietnam War.

b. The Fed increased the money supply to try to keep interest rates down.

As a result of these policies, the inflation rate remained fairly high. However, even though inflation remained high, unemployment did not remain low.

Figure 7

 


a. Figure 7 shows the inflation rate and the unemployment rate from 1961 to 1973. The simple inverse relationship between these two variables began to disappear in 1970.

b. This occurred because peoples inflation expectations adjusted to the higher rate of inflation and the unemployment rate returned to its natural rate of around 5 to 6 percent.

5. In the News: The Benefits of Low Expected Inflation

a. In the 1990s, the expected rate of inflation in the United States fell, which helped to keep the inflation rate low.

b. This is an article from The Wall Street Journal discussing this situation.

III.  Shifts in the Phillips Curve: The Role of Supply Shocks

A.  In 1974, OPEC increased the price of oil sharply. This increased the cost of producing many goods and services and therefore resulted in higher prices.

Figure 8

 


Definition of supply shock: an event that directly alters firms costs and prices, shifting the economys aggregate-supply curve and thus the Phillips curve.

Graphically, we could represent this supply shock as a shift in the short-run aggregate-supply curve to the left.

The decrease in equilibrium output and the increase in the price level left the economy with stagflation.

B. Given this turn of events, policymakers are left with a less favorable short-run tradeoff between unemployment and inflation.

If they increase aggregate demand to fight unemployment, they will raise inflation further.

If they lower aggregate demand to fight inflation, they will raise unemployment further.

C.  This less favorable tradeoff between unemployment and inflation can be shown by a shift of the short-run Phillips curve. The shift may be permanent or temporary, depending on how people adjust their expectations of inflation.

Figure 9

 


D.  During the 1970s, the Fed decided to accommodate the supply shock by increasing the supply of money. This increased the level of expected inflation. Figure 9 shows inflation and unemployment in the United States during the late 1970s and early 1980s.

IV.  The Cost of Reducing Inflation

A.  The Sacrifice Ratio



Figure 10

 


To reduce the inflation rate, the Fed must follow contractionary monetary policy.

a. When the Fed slows the rate of growth of the money supply, aggregate demand falls.

b. This reduces the level of output in the economy, increasing unemployment.

c. The economy moves from point A along the short-run Phillips curve to point B, which has a lower inflation rate but a higher unemployment rate.

d. Over time, people begin to adjust their inflation expectations downward and the short-run Phillips curve shifts. The economy moves from point B to point C, where inflation is lower and the unemployment rate is back to its natural rate.

Therefore, to reduce inflation, the economy must suffer through a period of high unemployment and low output.

Definition of sacrifice ratio: the number of percentage points of annual output lost in the process of reducing inflation by 1 percentage point.

A typical estimate of the sacrifice ratio is 5. This implies that for each percentage point inflation is decreased, output falls by 5 percent.

B. Rational Expectations and the Possibility of Costless Disinflation

Definition of rational expectations: the theory according to which people optimally use all the information they have, including information about government policies, when forecasting the future.

Proponents of rational expectations believe that when government policies change, people alter their expectations about inflation.

Therefore, if the government makes a credible commitment to a policy of low inflation, people would be rational enough to lower their expectations of inflation immediately. This implies that the short-run Phillips curve would shift quickly without any extended period of high unemployment.



C.  The Volcker Disinflation

Figure 11

 


Figure 11 shows the inflation and unemployment rates that occurred while Paul Volcker worked at reducing the level of inflation during the 1980s.

As inflation fell, unemployment rose. In fact, the United States experienced its deepest recession since the Great Depression.

Some economists have offered this as proof that the idea of a costless disinflation suggested by rational-expectations theorists is not possible. However, there are two reasons why we might not want to reject the rational-expectations theory so quickly.

a. The cost (in terms of lost output) of the Volcker disinflation was not as large as many economists had predicted.

b. While Volcker promised that he would fight inflation, many people did not believe him. Few people thought that inflation would fall as quickly as it did; this likely kept the short-run Phillips curve from shifting quickly.

D.  The Greenspan Era

Figure 12

 


Figure 12 shows the inflation and unemployment rate from 1984 to 1999, called the Greenspan era because Alan Greenspan became the chairman of the Federal Reserve in 1987.

In 1986, OPECs agreement with its members broke down and oil prices fell. The result of this favorable supply shock was a drop in both inflation and unemployment.

The rest of the 1990s witnessed a period of economic prosperity. Inflation gradually dropped, approaching zero by the end of the decade. Unemployment also reached a low level, leading many people to believe that the natural rate of unemployment has fallen.

The economy ran into problems in 2001 due to the end of the dot.com stock market bubble, the 9-11 terrorist attacks, and the corporate accounting scandals that reduced aggregate demand. Unemployment rose as the economy experienced its first recession in a decade.

5. Case Study: Why Were Inflation and Unemployment So Low at the End of the 1990s?

a. At the end of the 1990s, the unemployment rate and the inflation rate were lower than the United States had seen in many years.

b. This likely implies that the short-run Phillips curve has drifted leftward, giving the United States a more favorable tradeoff between inflation and unemployment.

c. Causes of this movement in the short-run Phillips curve include reductions in expected inflation, lower commodity prices, changes in the stability of the labor force, and technological advancements.

E. In the News: The Case for Targeting Inflation

Inflation targeting is a type of monetary policy that commits the central bank to a pursuit of an announced low inflation rate target.

This is an article by three economists suggesting that the Fed commit to this type of policy to ensure that the gains of the 1990s (in terms of low expected inflation) continue after Greenspan leaves the Fed.

SOLUTIONS TO TEXT PROBLEMS:

Quick Quizzes

1. The Phillips curve is shown in Figure 1.

Figure 1

To see how policy can move the economy from a point with high inflation to a point with low inflation, suppose the economy begins at point A in Figure 2. If policy is used to reduce aggregate demand (such as a decrease in the money supply or a decrease in government purchases), the aggregate-demand curve shifts from AD1 to AD2 and the economy moves from point A to point B with lower inflation.

Figure 2

Figure 3 shows the short-run Phillips curve and the long-run Phillips curve. The curves are different because in the long run, monetary policy has no effect on unemployment, which must be at its natural rate, but in the short run, monetary policy can shift aggregate demand, raising or lowering the inflation rate with the opposite effect on the unemployment rate.

Figure 3

Examples of a favorable shock to aggregate supply include improved productivity and a decline in oil prices. The shock shifts the aggregate-supply curve to the right, increasing output and reducing the price level, moving the economy from point A to point B in Figure 4. As a result, the Phillips curve shifts to the left, as the figure shows.

Figure 4

The sacrifice ratio is the number of percentage points of annual output lost in the process of reducing inflation by 1 percentage point. The credibility of the Feds commitment to reduce inflation might affect the sacrifice ratio because it affects the speed at which expectations of inflation adjust. If the Feds commitment to reduce inflation is credible, people will adjust their expectations of inflation quickly, the Phillips curve will shift left, and the cost of reducing inflation will be low. But if the Fed isnt credible, people will not adjust their expectations of inflation, and the cost of reducing inflation will be high.

Questions for Review

Figure 5

1. Figure 5 shows the short-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. The Fed can move from one point on this curve to another by changing the money supply. An increase in the money supply reduces the unemployment rate and increases the inflation rate, while a decrease in the money supply increases the unemployment rate and decreases the inflation rate.

Figure 6 shows the long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. In the long run, there is no tradeoff, as the economy must return to the natural rate of unemployment on the long-run Phillips curve. In the short run, the economy can move along a short-run Phillips curve, like SRPC1 shown in the figure. But over time (as inflation expectations adjust) the short-run Phillips curve will shift to return the economy to the long-run Phillips curve, for example shifting from SRPC1 to SRPC2.

Figure 6

The natural rate of unemployment is natural because it is beyond the influence of monetary policy. The rate of unemployment will move to its natural rate in the long run, regardless of the inflation rate.

The natural rate of unemployment might differ across countries because countries have varying degrees of union power, minimum-wage laws, collective-bargaining laws, unemployment insurance, job-training programs, and other factors that influence labor-market conditions.

If a drought destroys farm crops and drives up the price of food, the short-run aggregate-supply curve shifts up, as does the short-run Phillips curve, because the costs of production have increased. The higher short-run Phillips curve means the inflation rate will be higher for any given unemployment rate.

When the Fed decides to reduce inflation, the economy moves down along the short-run Phillips curve, as shown in Figure 7. Beginning at point A on short-run Phillips curve SRPC1, the economy moves down to point B as inflation declines. Once people's expectations adjust to the lower rate of inflation, the short-run Phillips curve shifts to SRPC2, and the economy moves to point C. The short-run costs of disinflation, which arise because the unemployment rate is temporarily above its natural rate, could be reduced if the Fed's action was credible, so that expectations would adjust more rapidly.

Figure 7

Problems and Applications

Figure 8 shows two different short-run Phillips curves depicting these four points. Points a and d are on SRPC1 because both have expected inflation of 3 percent. Points b and c are on SRPC2 because both have expected inflation of 5 percent.

Figure 8

2. a. A rise in the natural rate of unemployment shifts the long-run Phillips curve to the right, as shown in Figure 9. The economy is initially on LRPC1 and SRPC1 at an inflation rate of 3 percent, which is also the expected rate of inflation. The increase in the natural rate of unemployment shifts the long-run Phillips curve to LRPC2 and the short-run Phillips curve to SRPC2, with the expected rate of inflation remaining equal to 3 percent.

Figure 9

b. A decline in the price of imported oil shifts the short-run Phillips curve down, as shown in Figure 10, from SRPC1 to SRPC2. For any given unemployment rate, the inflation rate is lower, since oil is such a significant aspect of production costs in the economy.

Figure 10

c. A rise in government spending represents an increase in aggregate demand, so it moves the economy along the short-run Phillips curve, as shown in Figure 11. The economy moves from point A to point B, with a decline in the unemployment rate and an increase in the inflation rate.

Figure 11

d. A decline in expected inflation causes the short-run Phillips curve to shift down, as shown in Figure 12. The lower rate of expected inflation shifts the short-run Phillips curve from SRPC1 to SRPC2.

Figure 12

3. a. Figure 13 shows how a reduction in consumer spending causes a recession in both an aggregate-supply/aggregate-demand diagram and a Phillips-curve diagram. In both diagrams, the economy begins at full employment at point A. The decline in consumer spending reduces aggregate demand, shifting the aggregate-demand curve to the left from AD1 to AD2. The economy initially remains on the short-run aggregate-supply curve SRAS1, so the new equilibrium occurs at point B. The movement of the aggregate-demand curve along the short-run aggregate-supply curve leads to a movement along short-run Phillips curve SRPC1, from point A to point B. The lower price level in the aggregate-supply/aggregate-demand diagram corresponds to the lower inflation rate in the Phillips-curve diagram. The lower level of output in the aggregate-supply/aggregate-demand diagram corresponds to the higher unemployment rate in the Phillips-curve diagram.

b. As expected inflation falls over time, the short-run aggregate-supply curve shifts down from AS1 to AS2, and the short-run Phillips curve shifts down from SRPC1 to SRPC2. In both diagrams, the economy eventually gets to point C, which is back on the long-run aggregate-supply curve and long-run Phillips curve. After the recession is over, the economy faces a better set of inflation-unemployment combinations.

Figure 13

Figure 14

4. a. Figure 14 shows the economy in long-run equilibrium at point a, which is on both the long-run and short-run Phillips curves.

b. A wave of business pessimism reduces aggregate demand, moving the economy to point b in the figure. The unemployment rate rises and the inflation rate declines. If the Fed undertakes expansionary monetary policy, it can increase aggregate demand, offsetting the pessimism and returning the economy to point a, with the initial inflation rate and unemployment rate.

c. Figure 15 shows the effects on the economy if the price of imported oil rises. The higher price of imported oil shifts the short-run Phillips curve up from SRPC1 to SRPC2. The economy moves from point a to point c, with a higher inflation rate and higher unemployment rate. Now if the Fed engages in expansionary monetary policy, it can return the economy to its original unemployment rate at point d, but the inflation rate will be higher. If the Fed engages in contractionary monetary policy, it can return the economy to its original inflation rate at point e, but the unemployment rate will be higher. This situation differs from that in part (b) because in part (b) the economy stayed on the same short-run Phillips curve, but in part (c) the economy moved to a higher short-run Phillips curve, which gives policymakers a less favorable tradeoff between inflation and unemployment.

Figure 15

If the Fed acts on its belief that the natural rate of unemployment is 6 percent, when the natural rate is in fact 5.5 percent, the result will be a spiraling down of the inflation rate, as shown in Figure 16. Starting from a point on the long-run Phillips curve, with an unemployment rate of 5.5 percent, the Fed will think that the economy is overheating, since the unemployment rate is below what it thinks is the natural rate. So the Fed will contract the money supply, moving the economy along the short-run Phillips curve SRPC1. The inflation rate will decline and the unemployment rate will rise to 6 percent. As the inflation rate declines, people's expectations of inflation will eventually decline, and the short-run Phillips curve will shift to the left to SRPC2. This process will continue, and the inflation rate will spiral downwards.

Figure 16

Figure 17

6. a. Figure 17 shows the effects of a fall in the price of oil. The short-run aggregate-supply curve shifts to the right, reducing the price level and increasing the quantity of output. The short-run Phillips curve shifts to the left. In both diagrams, the economy moves from point A to point B. In equilibrium, both the inflation rate and the unemployment rate decline.

b. The effects of this event do not mean there is no short-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment, as shifts in aggregate demand still move the economy along the short-run Phillips curve.

a. If wage contracts have short durations, a recession induced by contractionary monetary policy will be less severe, since wage contracts can be adjusted more rapidly to reflect the lower inflation rate. This will allow a more rapid movement of the short-run aggregate-supply curve and short-run Phillips curve to restore the economy to long-run equilibrium.

b. If there is little confidence in the Fed's determination to reduce inflation, a recession induced by contractionary monetary policy will be more severe. It will take longer for people's inflation expectations to adjust downwards.

c. If expectations of inflation adjust quickly to actual inflation, a recession induced by contractionary monetary policy will be less severe. In this case, people's expectations adjust quickly, so the short-run Phillips curve shifts quickly to restore the economy to long-run equilibrium at the natural rate of unemployment.

Economists who believe the short-run Phillips curve is relatively steep and shifts quickly in response to changes in the economy would be more likely to favor using contractionary policy to reduce inflation than economists with the opposite views. If the short-run Phillips curve is relatively steep, then the unemployment rate does not rise much because of contractionary policy. And if the short-run Phillips curve shifts quickly in response to changes in the economy, then the economy will not be off of the long-run Phillips curve for long in response to contractionary monetary policy. Thus, the costs of disinflation will be very small.

If the Fed announces a disinflation, but nominal wages have been set in three-year contracts, then the lower rate of inflation will mean real wages are too high until the contracts can be renegotiated in three years. As a result, firms will not hire as much labor and the unemployment rate will exceed the natural rate, so the disinflation would be costly. To reduce the cost of disinflation, the Fed could announce that it would reduce inflation three years from now, so contracts could be adjusted. Alternatively, the Fed could reduce inflation very slowly, so real wages wouldn't be too high for long, and the costs of disinflation would be lower.

Even though inflation is unpopular, elected leaders do not always support efforts to reduce inflation because of the short-run costs associated with disinflation. In particular, as disinflation occurs, the unemployment rate rises, and when unemployment is high people tend not to vote for incumbent politicians, blaming them for the bad state of the economy. Thus politicians tend not to support disinflation.

Economists believe that countries with independent central banks can reduce the cost of disinflation because in those countries politicians cannot interfere with central banks' disinflation efforts. People will believe the central bank when it announces a disinflation because they know politicians cannot stop the disinflation. In countries with central banks that are not independent, people know that politicians who are worried they will not be reelected could stop a disinflation. As a result, the credibility of the central bank is lower and thus the costs of disinflation are higher.

If policymakers are uncertain about the value of the natural rate of unemployment (as was clearly the case in the 1990s, when economists were continually revising their estimates of the natural rate downward), they need to look at other variables. Since theres a correspondence through the Phillips curve between inflation and unemployment, when unemployment is close to its natural rate, inflation should not change. Thus, policymakers can look at data on the inflation rate to judge how close unemployment is to its natural rate. In addition, they can look at other macroeconomic variables, including the components of GDP and interest rates, to try to disentangle shifts in aggregate supply from shifts in aggregate demand, which (when combined with information about inflation) can help them determine the appropriate stance for monetary policy.





Politica de confidentialitate | Termeni si conditii de utilizare



});

DISTRIBUIE DOCUMENTUL

Comentarii


Vizualizari: 3726
Importanta: rank

Comenteaza documentul:

Te rugam sa te autentifici sau sa iti faci cont pentru a putea comenta

Creaza cont nou

Termeni si conditii de utilizare | Contact
© SCRIGROUP 2024 . All rights reserved